skip to main |
skip to sidebar
To Trade Is Human
Updated at Medianism.org
The Wall Street Journal summarized the work of some economic historians who argue that trade was the reason that puny humans took over the world: Evolution and Creativity: Why Humans Triumphed:
Nothing seems to explain the sudden takeoff of the last
45,000 years—the conversion of just another rare predatory ape into a
planet dominator with rapidly progressing technologies. Once
“progress” started to produce new tools, different ways of life and
burgeoning populations, it accelerated all over the world, culminating
in agriculture, cities, literacy and all the rest. Yet all the
ingredients of human success—tool making, big brains, culture, fire,
even language—seem to have been in place half a million years before
and nothing happened. Tools were made to the same monotonous design
for hundreds of thousands of years and the ecological impact of people
was minimal. Then suddenly—bang!—culture exploded, starting in
Africa. Why then, why there? The answer lies in a new idea, borrowed
from economics, known as collective intelligence: the notion that what
determines the inventiveness and rate of cultural change of a
population is the amount of interaction between individuals….
Scientists have so far been looking for the answer to this riddle in
the wrong place: inside human heads. Most have been expecting to find
a sort of neural or genetic breakthrough that sparked a “big bang of
human consciousness,” an auspicious mutation so that people could
speak, think or plan better, setting the human race on the path to
continuous and exponential innovation. But the sophistication of the
modern world lies not in individual intelligence or imagination. It is a
collective enterprise. Nobody—literally nobody—knows how to make the
pencil on my desk ...let alone the computer on which I am writing…
We tend to forget that trade and urbanization are the grand stimuli
to invention, far more important than ...individual
genius. It is no coincidence that trade-obsessed cities—Tyre, Athens,
Alexandria, Baghdad, Pisa, Amsterdam, London, Hong Kong, New York,
Tokyo, San Francisco—are the places where invention and discovery
happened. Think of them as well-endowed collective brains. Trade also
gave way to centralized institutions…
Agriculture was invented where people were already living in dense trading societies….
Go even further back and you find the same thing. The explosion of
new technologies for hunting and gathering in western Asia around
45,000 years ago, often called the Upper Paleolithic Revolution,
occurred in an area with an especially dense population of
hunter-gatherers—with a bigger collective brain. Long before the
ancestors of modern people first set foot outside Africa, there was
cultural progress within Africa itself, but it had a strangely
intermittent, ephemeral quality: There would be flowerings of new tool
kits and new ways of life, which then faded again….
Trade is to culture as sex is to biology. Exchange makes cultural
change collective and cumulative. It becomes possible to draw upon
inventions made throughout society, not just in your neighborhood. The
rate of cultural and economic progress depends on the rate at which
ideas are having sex.
Dense populations don’t produce innovation in other species. They
only do so in human beings, because only human beings indulge in regular
exchange of different items among unrelated, unmated individuals and
even among strangers. So here is the answer to the puzzle of human
takeoff. It was caused by the invention of a collective brain itself
made possible by the invention of exchange.
Once human beings started swapping things and thoughts, they
stumbled upon divisions of labor, in which specialization led to
mutually beneficial collective knowledge. Specialization is the means
by which exchange encourages innovation: In getting better at making
your product or delivering your service, you come up with new tools.
The story of the human race has been a gradual spread of specialization
and exchange ever since: Prosperity consists of getting more and more
narrow in what you make and more and more diverse in what you buy.
Self-sufficiency—subsistence—is poverty….
This theory neatly explains why some parts of the world lagged
behind in their rate of cultural evolution after the Upper Paleolithic
takeoff. Australia, though it was colonized by modern people 20,000
years earlier than most of Europe, saw comparatively slow change in
technology and never experienced the transition to farming. This might
have been because its dry and erratic climate never allowed
hunter-gatherers to reach high enough densities of interaction to
indulge in more than a little specialization.
Where population falls or is fragmented, cultural evolution may
actually regress. A telling example comes from Tasmania, where people
who had been making bone tools, clothing and fishing equipment for
25,000 years gradually gave these up after being isolated by rising sea
levels 10,000 years ago. Joe Henrich of the University of British
Columbia argues that the population of 4,000 Tasmanians on the island
constituted too small a collective brain to sustain, let alone improve,
the existing technology.
The oldest evidence for human trade comes from roughly 80,000 to
120,000 years ago, when shell beads in Algeria and obsidian tools in
Ethiopia began to move more than 100 miles from the sea and from a
particular volcano respectively. (In recent centuries stone tools moved
such distances in Australia by trade rather than by migration.) This
first stirring of trade was the most momentous innovation of the human
species, because it led to the invention of invention. Why it happened
in Africa remains a puzzle, but Steve Kuhn and Mary Stiner of the
University of Arizona have argued that for some reason only Africans had
invented a sexual division of labor between male hunters and female
gatherers—the most basic of all trades….
The process of cumulative innovation that has doubled life span, cut
child mortality by three-quarters and multiplied per capita income
ninefold—world-wide—in little more than a century is driven by ideas
having sex. And things like the search engine, the mobile phone and
container shipping just made ideas a whole lot more promiscuous still.
The article also talks about Neanderthals:
Neanderthals are now known to have had brains that were
bigger than ours and to have inherited the same genetic mutations that
facilitate speech as us. Yet, despite surviving until 30,000 years
ago, they hardly invented any new tools, let alone farms, cities and
toothpaste. The Neanderthals prove that it is quite possible to be
intelligent and imaginative human beings (they buried their dead) yet
not experience cultural and economic progress.
Further proof that exchange and collective intelligence are the key
to human progress comes from Neanderthal remains. Almost all
Neanderthal tools are found close to their likely site of origin: they
did not trade. In the southern Caucasus, argues Daniel Adler of the
University of Connecticut, it is the “development and maintenance of
larger social networks, rather than technological innovations or
increased hunting prowess, that distinguish modern humans from
Neanderthals.
Our ancestors (Homo sapiens) displaced Neanderthal man (Homo
neanderthalensis) despite our competitors having larger brains and much
stronger bodies. They had tools and speech and buried their dead. Jason Shogren argues that the only advantage our ancestors had over Neanderthal man is that Homo sapiens was much more inclined to trade:
SINCE the days of Adam Smith and David Ricardo, advocates
of free trade and the division of labour, …have lauded the advantages
of those economic principles. Until now, though, no one has suggested
that they might be responsible for the very existence of humanity. But
that is the thesis propounded by Jason Shogren, … For Dr Shogren is
suggesting that trade and specialisation are the reasons Homo sapiens displaced previous members of the genus, such as Homo neanderthalensis (Neanderthal man), and emerged triumphant as the only species of humanity.
Neanderthal man has had a bad cultural rap over the years since the
discovery of the first specimen in the Neander valley in Germany, in the
mid-19th century. The “caveman” image of a stupid, grunting, hairy,
thick-skulled parody of graceful modern humanity has stuck in the public
consciousness. But current scholarship suggests Neanderthals were
probably about as smart as modern humans, and also capable of speech. If
they were hairy, strong and tough—which they were—that was an
appropriate adaptation to the ice-age conditions in which they lived. So
why did they become extinct?
Neanderthals existed perfectly successfully for 200,000 years before Homo sapiens arrived
in their European homeland about 40,000 years ago, …. But 10,000 years
later they were gone, so it seems likely that the arrival of modern
man was the cause. The two species certainly occupied more or less the
same ecological niche (hunting a wide range of animals, and gathering a
similarly eclectic range of plant food), and would thus have been
competitors…. according to Dr Shogren’s paper in a forthcoming edition
of the Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation, it was neither cave paintings nor better spear points that led to Homo sapiens‘s dominance. It was a better economic system.
One thing Homo sapiens does that Homo neanderthalensis shows
no sign of having done is trade. The evidence suggests that such trade
was going on even 40,000 years ago. Stone tools made of non-local
materials, and sea-shell jewellery found far from the coast, are
witnesses to long-distance exchanges. That Homo sapiens also
practised division of labour and specialisation is suggested not only by
the skilled nature of his craft work, but also by the fact that his
dwellings had spaces apparently set aside for different uses…. Only in
the case of the trading and specialisation variables did they allow Homo sapiens an
advantage: specifically, they assumed that the most efficient human
hunters specialised in hunting, while bad hunters hung up their spears
and made things such as clothes and tools instead. Hunters and craftsmen
then traded with one another.
According to the model, this arrangement resulted in everyone getting
more meat, which drove up fertility and thus increased the population.
Since the supply of meat was finite, that left less for Neanderthals,
and their population declined…. the presence of a trading economy in
the modern human population can result in the extermination of
Neanderthals even if the latter are at an advantage in traditional
biological attributes, such as hunting ability.
Both trade and technology finally had an enduring expansion during
the “upper paleolithic explosion” about 40,000 years ago. The above
reading argues that it was due to population density. Haim Ofek’s book
argues that this was due to the invention of money. He argues that
this was the time when there was a blossoming of symbolic expression
like sculpture and cave paintings. Money is nothing more than a
symbolic representation of value and so a culture that widely engages
in symbolic artistic representation may also ‘get’ the idea that rare
beads are worth trading for food or stone blades.
No comments:
Post a Comment