Via Dylan Matthews, the Hamilton Project has the great summary chart (above) comparing the findings about the short-term economic impact of immigration from two major studies by economists. I'm more of an Ottaviano-Peri man than a Borjas-Katz man because I believe in complementarity, the idea that immigrant workers increase the demand for skills (English language competence, for example) that even 'unskilled' U.S.-born workers have.Kevin Drum explains the politics further:
What it also shows you is that the actual economics of immigration are totally irrelevant to the political debate. The voters most likely to oppose high levels of immigration are precisely the people who Borjas and Katz say benefit from it economically. Meanwhile, immigration supporters and especially Spanish-dominant Latinos often feel the negative wage impact of immigration, since that's where complementarity plays the least role. In other words, if the immigration issue were about economics, then you'd see white working-class voters clamoring for amnesty and open borders while SEIU and MALDEF emphasized the need to secure the border before taking any further steps.Of course you don't see that at all...
John Tanton, the founder of FAIR, the nation’s oldest and most influential immigration restriction group... tried to preach an anti-immigration message based on economic and conservation grounds. But it didn't work. Chris tells us what did work:How much of general globalization opposition is also due to cultural issues rather than economic ones?
Crisscrossing the country, Tanton found little interest in his conservation-based arguments for reduced immigration, but kept hearing the same complaint. “‘I tell you what pisses me off,’” Tanton recalls people saying. “‘It’s going into a ballot box and finding a ballot in a language I can’t read.’ So it became clear that the language question had a lot more emotional power than the immigration question.”Cultural insecurity and language angst are the key issues here. It doesn't matter if they're rational or not.
Tanton tried to persuade FAIR to harness this “emotional power,” but the board declined. So in 1983, Tanton sent out a fundraising letter on behalf of a new group he created called U.S. English. Typically, Tanton says, direct mail garners a contribution from around 1 percent of recipients. “The very first mailing we ever did for U.S. English got almost a 10 percent return,” he says. “That’s unheard of.” John Tanton had discovered the power of the culture war.
The success of U.S. English taught Tanton a crucial lesson. If the immigration restriction movement was to succeed, it would have to be rooted in an emotional appeal to those who felt that their country, their language, their very identity was under assault. “Feelings,” Tanton says in a tone reminiscent of Spock sharing some hard-won insight on human behavior, “trump facts.”
The reason immigration benefits native workers is that they are more complimentary for native workers rather than substitutes which makes native workers more productive. The same is true for capital goods. If robots make your labor more productive, then they will raise your wage, but if they are substitutes for your labor, then they will lower your wage. Immigration has increased the supply of dishwashers and busboys which has let native-born Americans move up to higher-paid employment as waiters, chefs, and making kitchen equipment. Moneybox:
The research that really changed my thinking on this is ably covered in this great Heidi Shierholz did for EPI back in February 2010. Note that EPI is the premiere labor-liberal think tank in Washington and hardly a hotbed of apologism for the top one percent. The basic point here is that the old CW on low-skill immigration is that it raised real wages for high-skill workers but lowered them for low-skill workers. The key methodological advance comes from realizing that a very large share of low-skill workers in the United States are themselves immigrants. Since restricting low-skill immigration for the sake of low-skill immigrants is a little perverse, it's helpful to distinguish between the impact on immigrant workers and native-born workers.
Here's what they found:
One key finding here is that if you look at typical native-born working class Americans—folks with high school diplomas but no college degree—they win out thanks to immigration. And even if you restrict your attention to U.S.-born high school dropouts they win under most scenarios.The losses from increased labor market competition are very real but they're concentrated among other immigrants. That's because it's all about complements. An increased supply of dishwashers and busboys increases the value of modestly educated people with complementary skills. To return to the restaurant, a waiter or a bartender needs to be able to speak English. In a world with no immigrants "can speak English" isn't much of a skill but when low-skill immigrants rush in suddenly it is. The people who lose out are the other workers who can't speak English, or who have specialized taco-making skills, or otherwise are extremely similar to new immigrants.